Newsvendor model Newsvendor Model - MywallpapersMobi

Newsvendor model Newsvendor Model

Newsvendor model

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Jump to navigation
Jump to search

The newsvendor (or newsboy or single-period [1] or perishable) model is a mathematical model in operations management and applied economics used to determine optimal inventory levels. It is (typically) characterized by fixed prices and uncertain demand for a perishable product. If the inventory level is




q


\displaystyle q

, each unit of demand above




q


\displaystyle q

aria-hidden=”true” style=”vertical-align: -0.671ex; width:1.07ex; height:2.009ex;” alt=”q”/> is lost in potential sales. This model is also known as the newsvendor problem or newsboy problem by analogy with the situation faced by a newspaper vendor who must decide how many copies of the day’s paper to stock in the face of uncertain demand and knowing that unsold copies will be worthless at the end of the day.

Contents

  • 1 History
  • 2 Profit function and the critical fractile formula
  • 3 Numerical examples
    • 3.1 Uniform distribution
    • 3.2 Normal distribution
    • 3.3 Lognormal distribution
    • 3.4 Extreme situation
  • 4 Derivation of optimal inventory level
  • 5 Alternative formulation
  • 6 Cost based optimization of inventory level
  • 7 Data-driven models
  • 8 See also
  • 9 References
  • 10 Further reading

History[ edit ]

The mathematical problem appears to date from 1888 [2] where Edgeworth used the central limit theorem to determine the optimal cash reserves to satisfy random withdrawals from depositors. [3]
According to Chen, Cheng, Choi and Wang (2016), the term “newsboy” was first mentioned in an example of the Morse and Kimball (1951)’s book/ [4] The modern formulation relates to a paper in Econometrica by Kenneth Arrow , T. Harris, and Jacob Marshak . [5]

Profit function and the critical fractile formula[ edit ]

The standard newsvendor profit function is




E

[

profit

]
=
E


[

p
min
(
q
,
D
)

]


c
q


\displaystyle \operatorname E [\textprofit]=\operatorname E \left[p\min(q,D)\right]-cq

where




D


\displaystyle D

is a random variable with probability distribution




F


\displaystyle F

representing demand, each unit is sold for price




p


\displaystyle p

and purchased for price




c


\displaystyle c

,




q


\displaystyle q

is the number of units stocked, and




E


\displaystyle E

is the expectation operator . The solution to the optimal stocking quantity of the newsvendor which maximizes expected profit is:

Critical fractile formula




q
=

F


1



(



p

c

p


)



\displaystyle q=F^-1\left(\frac p-cp\right)

where





F


1




\displaystyle F^-1

denotes the inverse cumulative distribution function of




D


\displaystyle D

.

Intuitively, this ratio, referred to as the critical fractile, balances the cost of being understocked (a lost sale worth




(
p

c
)


\displaystyle (p-c)

) and the total costs of being either overstocked or understocked (where the cost of being overstocked is the inventory cost, or




c


\displaystyle c

so total cost is simply




p


\displaystyle p

).

The critical fractile formula is known as Littlewood’s rule in the yield management literature.

Numerical examples[ edit ]

In the following cases, assume that the retail price,




p


\displaystyle p

, is $7 per unit and the purchase price is




c


\displaystyle c

, is $5 per unit. This gives a critical fractile of







p

c

p


=



7

5

7


=


2
7




\displaystyle \frac p-cp=\frac 7-57=\frac 27

Uniform distribution[ edit ]

Let demand,




D


\displaystyle D

, follow a uniform distribution (continuous) between





D

min


=
50


\displaystyle D_\min =50

and





D

max


=
80


\displaystyle D_\max =80

.





q

opt


=

F


1



(



7

5

7


)

=

F


1



(
0.285
)

=

D

min


+
(

D

max




D

min


)

0.285
=
58.55

59.


\displaystyle q_\textopt=F^-1\left(\frac 7-57\right)=F^-1\left(0.285\right)=D_\min +(D_\max -D_\min )\cdot 0.285=58.55\approx 59.

Therefore, optimal inventory level is approximately 59 units.

Normal distribution[ edit ]

Let demand,




D


\displaystyle D

, follow a normal distribution with a mean,




μ


\displaystyle \mu

, demand of 50 and a standard deviation ,




σ


\displaystyle \sigma

, of 20.





q

opt


=

F


1



(



7

5

7


)

=
μ
+
σ

Z


1



(
0.285
)

=
50
+
20
(

0.56595
)
=
38.68

39.


\displaystyle q_\textopt=F^-1\left(\frac 7-57\right)=\mu +\sigma Z^-1\left(0.285\right)=50+20(-0.56595)=38.68\approx 39.

Therefore, optimal inventory level is approximately 39 units.

Lognormal distribution[ edit ]

Let demand,




D


\displaystyle D

, follow a lognormal distribution with a mean demand of 50,




μ


\displaystyle \mu

, and a standard deviation ,




σ


\displaystyle \sigma

, of 0.2.





q

opt


=

F


1



(



7

5

7


)

=
μ

e


Z


1



(
0.285
)

σ


=
50

e


(

0.2

(

0.56595
)

)



=
44.64

45.


\displaystyle q_\textopt=F^-1\left(\frac 7-57\right)=\mu e^Z^-1\left(0.285\right)\sigma =50e^\left(0.2\cdot (-0.56595)\right)=44.64\approx 45.

Therefore, optimal inventory level is approximately 45 units.

Extreme situation[ edit ]

If




p
<
c


\displaystyle p<c

(i.e. the retail price is less than the purchase price), the numerator becomes negative. In this situation, it isn’t worth keeping any items in the inventory.

Derivation of optimal inventory level[ edit ]

To derive the critical fractile formula, start with




E


[

min

q
,
D


]



\displaystyle \operatorname E \left[\min\q,D\\right]

and condition on the event




D

q


\displaystyle D\leq q

:




E

[
min

q
,
D

]
=
E

[
min

q
,
D


D

q
]
P

(
D

q
)
+
E

[
min

q
,
D


D
>
q
]
P

(
D
>
q
)
=
E

[
D

D

q
]
F
(
q
)
+
E

[
q

D
>
q
]
[
1

F
(
q
)
]
=
E

[
D

D

q
]
F
(
q
)
+
q
[
1

F
(
q
)
]


\displaystyle \operatorname E [\min\q,D\]=\operatorname E [\min\q,D\\mid D\leq q]\operatorname P (D\leq q)+\operatorname E [\min\q,D\\mid D>q]\operatorname P (D>q)=\operatorname E [D\mid D\leq q]F(q)+\operatorname E [q\mid D>q][1-F(q)]=\operatorname E [D\mid D\leq q]F(q)+q[1-F(q)]

Now use




E

[
D

D

q
]
=






x

q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x





x

q


f
(
x
)

d
x





\displaystyle \operatorname E [D\mid D\leq q]=\frac \int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx\int \limits _x\leq qf(x)\,dx

, where




f
(
x
)
=

F


(
x
)


\displaystyle f(x)=F'(x)

. The denominator of this expression is




F
(
q
)


\displaystyle F(q)

, so now we can write:




E

[
min

q
,
D

]
=



x

q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x
+
q
[
1

F
(
q
)
]


\displaystyle \operatorname E [\min\q,D\]=\int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx+q[1-F(q)]

So




E

[

profit

]
=
p



x

q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x
+
p
q
[
1

F
(
q
)
]

c
q


\displaystyle \operatorname E [\textprofit]=p\int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx+pq[1-F(q)]-cq

Take the derivative with respect to




q


\displaystyle q

:









q



E

[

profit

]
=
p
q
f
(
q
)
+
p
q
(


F


(
q
)
)
+
p
[
1

F
(
q
)
]

c
=
p
[
1

F
(
q
)
]

c


\displaystyle \frac \partial \partial q\operatorname E [\textprofit]=pqf(q)+pq(-F'(q))+p[1-F(q)]-c=p[1-F(q)]-c

Now optimize:




p

[

1

F
(

q




)

]


c
=
0

1

F
(

q




)
=


c
p



F
(

q




)
=



p

c

p




q




=

F


1



(



p

c

p


)



\displaystyle p\left[1-F(q^*)\right]-c=0\Rightarrow 1-F(q^*)=\frac cp\Rightarrow F(q^*)=\frac p-cp\Rightarrow q^*=F^-1\left(\frac p-cp\right)

Technically, we should also check for convexity:









2





q

2





E

[

profit

]
=
p
[


F


(
q
)
]


\displaystyle \frac \partial ^2\partial q^2\operatorname E [\textprofit]=p[-F'(q)]

Since




F


\displaystyle F

is monotone non-decreasing, this second derivative is always non-positive, so the critical point determined above is a global maximum.

Alternative formulation[ edit ]

The problem above is cast as one of maximizing profit, although it can be cast slightly differently, with the same result. If the demand D exceeds the provided quantity q, then an opportunity cost of




(
D

q
)
(
p

c
)


\displaystyle (D-q)(p-c)

represents lost revenue not realized because of a shortage of inventory. On the other hand, if




D

q


\displaystyle D\leq q

, then (because the items being sold are perishable), there is an overage cost of




(
q

D
)
c


\displaystyle (q-D)c

. This problem can also be posed as one of minimizing the expectation of the sum of the opportunity cost and the overage cost, keeping in mind that only one of these is ever incurred for any particular realization of




D


\displaystyle D

. The derivation of this is as follows:









E

[

opportunity cost

+

overage cost

]




=




E

[

overage cost


D

q
]
P

(
D

q
)
+
E

[

opportunity cost


D
>
q
]
P

(
D
>
q
)




=




E

[
(
q

D
)
c

D

q
]
F
(
q
)
+
E

[
(
D

q
)
(
p

c
)

D
>
q
]
[
1

F
(
q
)
]




=




c
E

[
q

D

D

q
]
F
(
q
)
+
(
p

c
)
E

[
D

q

D
>
q
]
[
1

F
(
q
)
]




=




c
q
F
(
q
)

c



x

q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x
+
(
p

c
)
[



x
>
q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x

q
(
1

F
(
q
)
)
]




=




p



x
>
q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x

p
q
(
1

F
(
q
)
)

c



x
>
q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x
+
c
q
(
1

F
(
q
)
)
+
c
q
F
(
q
)

c



x

q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x




=




p



x
>
q


x
f
(
x
)

d
x

p
q
+
p
q
F
(
q
)
+
c
q

c
E

[
D
]






{\displaystyle {\beginaligned&\operatorname E [\textopportunity cost+\textoverage cost]\\[6pt]={}&\operatorname E [\textoverage cost\mid D\leq q]\operatorname P (D\leq q)+\operatorname E [\textopportunity cost\mid D>q]\operatorname P (D>q)\\[6pt]={}&\operatorname E [(q-D)c\mid D\leq q]F(q)+\operatorname E [(D-q)(p-c)\mid D>q][1-F(q)]\\[6pt]={}&c\operatorname E [q-D\mid D\leq q]F(q)+(p-c)\operatorname E [D-q\mid D>q][1-F(q)]\\[6pt]={}&cqF(q)-c\int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx+(p-c)[\int \limits _x>qxf(x)\,dx-q(1-F(q))]\\[6pt]={}&p\int \limits _x>qxf(x)\,dx-pq(1-F(q))-c\int \limits _x>qxf(x)\,dx+cq(1-F(q))+cqF(q)-c\int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx\\[6pt]={}&p\int \limits _x>qxf(x)\,dx-pq+pqF(q)+cq-c\operatorname E [D]\endaligned}}

The derivative of this expression, with respect to




q


\displaystyle q

, is









q



E

[

opportunity cost

+

overage cost

]
=
p
(

q
f
(
q
)
)

p
+
p
q

F


(
q
)
+
p
F
(
q
)
+
c
=
p
F
(
q
)
+
c

p


\displaystyle \frac \partial \partial q\operatorname E [\textopportunity cost+\textoverage cost]=p(-qf(q))-p+pqF'(q)+pF(q)+c=pF(q)+c-p

This is obviously the negative of the derivative arrived at above, and this is a minimization instead of a maximization formulation, so the critical point will be the same.

Cost based optimization of inventory level[ edit ]

Assume that the ‘newsvendor’ is in fact a small company that wants to produce goods to an uncertain market. In this more general situation the cost function of the newsvendor (company) can be formulated in the following manner:




K
(
q
)
=

c

f


+

c

v


(
q

x
)
+
p
E


[

max
(
D

q
,
0
)

]

+
h
E


[

max
(
q

D
,
0
)

]



\displaystyle K(q)=c_f+c_v(q-x)+p\operatorname E \left[\max(D-q,0)\right]+h\operatorname E \left[\max(q-D,0)\right]

where the individual parameters are the following:






  • c

    f




    \displaystyle c_f

    – fixed cost. This cost always exists when the production of a series is started. [$/production]






  • c

    v




    \displaystyle c_v

    – variable cost. This cost type expresses the production cost of one product. [$/product]





  • q


    \displaystyle q

    – the product quantity in the inventory. The decision of the inventory control policy concerns the product quantity in the inventory after the product decision. This parameter includes the initial inventory as well. If nothing is produced, then this quantity is equal to the initial quantity, i.e. concerning the existing inventory.





  • x


    \displaystyle x

    – initial inventory level. We assume that the supplier possesses




    x


    \displaystyle x

    products in the inventory at the beginning of the demand of the delivery period.





  • p


    \displaystyle p

    – penalty cost (or back order cost). If there is less raw material in the inventory than needed to satisfy the demands, this is the penalty cost of the unsatisfied orders. [$/product]





  • D


    \displaystyle D

    – a random variable with cumulative distribution function




    F


    \displaystyle F

    representing uncertain customer demand. [unit]





  • E
    [
    D
    ]


    \displaystyle E[D]

    – expected value of random variable




    D


    \displaystyle D

    .





  • h


    \displaystyle h

    – inventory and stock holding cost. [$ / product]

In




K
(
q
)


\displaystyle K(q)

, the first order loss function




E

[

max
(
D

q
,
0
)

]



\displaystyle E\left[\max(D-q,0)\right]

captures the expected shortage quantity; its complement,




E

[

max
(
q

D
,
0
)

]



\displaystyle E\left[\max(q-D,0)\right]

, denotes the expected product quantity in stock at the end of the period. [6]

On the basis of this cost function the determination of the optimal inventory level is a minimization problem. So in the long run the amount of cost-optimal end-product can be calculated on the basis of the following relation: [1]





q

opt


=

F


1



(



p


c

v




p
+
h



)



\displaystyle q_\textopt=F^-1\left(\frac p-c_vp+h\right)

Data-driven models[ edit ]

There are several data-driven model for the newsvendor problem. Among them, a deep learning model provides quite stable results in any kind of non-noisy or volatile data. [7]

See also[ edit ]

  • Infinite fill rate for the part being produced: Economic order quantity
  • Constant fill rate for the part being produced: Economic production quantity
  • Demand varies over time: Dynamic lot size model
  • Several products produced on the same machine: Economic lot scheduling problem
  • Reorder point
  • Inventory control system
  • Extended newsvendor model

References[ edit ]

  1. ^ a b William J. Stevenson, Operations Management. 10th edition, 2009; page 581
  2. ^ F. Y. Edgeworth (1888). “The Mathematical Theory of Banking”. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. 51 (1): 113–127. JSTOR   2979084 .

  3. ^ Guillermo Gallego (18 Jan 2005). “IEOR 4000 Production Management Lecture 7” (PDF). Columbia University . Retrieved 30 May 2012.
  4. ^ R. R. Chen; T.C.E. Cheng; T.M. Choi; Y. Wang (2016). “Novel Advances in Applications of the Newsvendor Model”. Decision Sciences. 47: 8–10.
  5. ^ K. J. Arrow, T. Harris, Jacob Marshak, Optimal Inventory Policy, Econometrica 1951
  6. ^ Axsäter, Sven (2015). Inventory Control (3rd ed.). Springer International Publishing. ISBN   978-3-319-15729-0 .
  7. ^ Oroojlooyjadid, Afshin; Snyder, Lawrence; Takáč, Martin (2016-07-07). “Applying Deep Learning to the Newsvendor Problem”. arXiv : 1607.02177 [ cs.LG ].

Further reading[ edit ]

  • Ayhan, Hayriye, Dai, Jim, Foley, R. D., Wu, Joe, 2004: Newsvendor Notes, ISyE 3232 Stochastic Manufacturing & Service Systems. [1]
  • Tsan-Ming Choi (Ed.) Handbook of Newsvendor Problems: Models, Extensions and Applications, in Springer’s International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, 2012.

Retrieved from ” https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Newsvendor_model&oldid=846789040 ”
Categories :

  • Inventory optimization

Navigation menu

Personal tools

  • Not logged in
  • Talk
  • Contributions
  • Create account
  • Log in

Namespaces

  • Article
  • Talk

Variants

    Views

    • Read
    • Edit
    • View history

    More


      Navigation

      • Main page
      • Contents
      • Featured content
      • Current events
      • Random article
      • Donate to Wikipedia
      • Wikipedia store

      Interaction

      • Help
      • About Wikipedia
      • Community portal
      • Recent changes
      • Contact page

      Tools

      • What links here
      • Related changes
      • Upload file
      • Special pages
      • Permanent link
      • Page information
      • Wikidata item
      • Cite this page

      Print/export

      • Create a book
      • Download as PDF
      • Printable version

      Languages

      • Deutsch
      • Español
      • Euskara
      • Français
      • Italiano
      • Polski
      • Português
      Edit links

      • This page was last edited on 20 June 2018, at 22:12 (UTC).
      • Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License ;
        additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy . Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc. , a non-profit organization.
      • Privacy policy
      • About Wikipedia
      • Disclaimers
      • Contact Wikipedia
      • Developers
      • Cookie statement
      • Mobile view
      • Wikimedia Foundation
      • Powered by MediaWiki

      Newsvendor model

      From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

      Jump to navigation
      Jump to search

      The newsvendor (or newsboy or single-period [1] or perishable) model is a mathematical model in operations management and applied economics used to determine optimal inventory levels. It is (typically) characterized by fixed prices and uncertain demand for a perishable product. If the inventory level is




      q


      \displaystyle q

      , each unit of demand above




      q


      \displaystyle q

      is lost in potential sales. This model is also known as the newsvendor problem or newsboy problem by analogy with the situation faced by a newspaper vendor who must decide how many copies of the day’s paper to stock in the face of uncertain demand and knowing that unsold copies will be worthless at the end of the day.

      Contents

      • 1 History
      • 2 Profit function and the critical fractile formula
      • 3 Numerical examples
        • 3.1 Uniform distribution
        • 3.2 Normal distribution
        • 3.3 Lognormal distribution
        • 3.4 Extreme situation
      • 4 Derivation of optimal inventory level
      • 5 Alternative formulation
      • 6 Cost based optimization of inventory level
      • 7 Data-driven models
      • 8 See also
      • 9 References
      • 10 Further reading

      History[ edit ]

      The mathematical problem appears to date from 1888 [2] where Edgeworth used the central limit theorem to determine the optimal cash reserves to satisfy random withdrawals from depositors. [3]
      According to Chen, Cheng, Choi and Wang (2016), the term “newsboy” was first mentioned in an example of the Morse and Kimball (1951)’s book/ [4] The modern formulation relates to a paper in Econometrica by Kenneth Arrow , T. Harris, and Jacob Marshak . [5]

      Profit function and the critical fractile formula[ edit ]

      The standard newsvendor profit function is




      E

      [

      profit

      ]
      =
      E


      [

      p
      min
      (
      q
      ,
      D
      )

      ]


      c
      q


      \displaystyle \operatorname E [\textprofit]=\operatorname E \left[p\min(q,D)\right]-cq

      where




      D


      \displaystyle D

      is a random variable with probability distribution




      F


      \displaystyle F

      representing demand, each unit is sold for price




      p


      \displaystyle p

      and purchased for price




      c


      \displaystyle c

      ,




      q


      \displaystyle q

      is the number of units stocked, and




      E


      \displaystyle E

      is the expectation operator . The solution to the optimal stocking quantity of the newsvendor which maximizes expected profit is:

      Critical fractile formula




      q
      =

      F


      1



      (



      p

      c

      p


      )



      \displaystyle q=F^-1\left(\frac p-cp\right)

      where





      F


      1




      \displaystyle F^-1

      denotes the inverse cumulative distribution function of




      D


      \displaystyle D

      .

      Intuitively, this ratio, referred to as the critical fractile, balances the cost of being understocked (a lost sale worth




      (
      p

      c
      )


      \displaystyle (p-c)

      ) and the total costs of being either overstocked or understocked (where the cost of being overstocked is the inventory cost, or




      c


      \displaystyle c

      so total cost is simply




      p


      \displaystyle p

      ).

      The critical fractile formula is known as Littlewood’s rule in the yield management literature.

      Numerical examples[ edit ]

      In the following cases, assume that the retail price,




      p


      \displaystyle p

      , is $7 per unit and the purchase price is




      c


      \displaystyle c

      , is $5 per unit. This gives a critical fractile of







      p

      c

      p


      =



      7

      5

      7


      =


      2
      7




      \displaystyle \frac p-cp=\frac 7-57=\frac 27

      Uniform distribution[ edit ]

      Let demand,




      D


      \displaystyle D

      , follow a uniform distribution (continuous) between





      D

      min


      =
      50


      \displaystyle D_\min =50

      and





      D

      max


      =
      80


      \displaystyle D_\max =80

      .





      q

      opt


      =

      F


      1



      (



      7

      5

      7


      )

      =

      F


      1



      (
      0.285
      )

      =

      D

      min


      +
      (

      D

      max




      D

      min


      )

      0.285
      =
      58.55

      59.


      \displaystyle q_\textopt=F^-1\left(\frac 7-57\right)=F^-1\left(0.285\right)=D_\min +(D_\max -D_\min )\cdot 0.285=58.55\approx 59.

      Therefore, optimal inventory level is approximately 59 units.

      Normal distribution[ edit ]

      Let demand,




      D


      \displaystyle D

      , follow a normal distribution with a mean,




      μ


      \displaystyle \mu

      , demand of 50 and a standard deviation ,




      σ


      \displaystyle \sigma

      , of 20.





      q

      opt


      =

      F


      1



      (



      7

      5

      7


      )

      =
      μ
      +
      σ

      Z


      1



      (
      0.285
      )

      =
      50
      +
      20
      (

      0.56595
      )
      =
      38.68

      39.


      \displaystyle q_\textopt=F^-1\left(\frac 7-57\right)=\mu +\sigma Z^-1\left(0.285\right)=50+20(-0.56595)=38.68\approx 39.

      Therefore, optimal inventory level is approximately 39 units.

      Lognormal distribution[ edit ]

      Let demand,




      D


      \displaystyle D

      , follow a lognormal distribution with a mean demand of 50,




      μ


      \displaystyle \mu

      , and a standard deviation ,




      σ


      \displaystyle \sigma

      , of 0.2.





      q

      opt


      =

      F


      1



      (



      7

      5

      7


      )

      =
      μ

      e


      Z


      1



      (
      0.285
      )

      σ


      =
      50

      e


      (

      0.2

      (

      0.56595
      )

      )



      =
      44.64

      45.


      \displaystyle q_\textopt=F^-1\left(\frac 7-57\right)=\mu e^Z^-1\left(0.285\right)\sigma =50e^\left(0.2\cdot (-0.56595)\right)=44.64\approx 45.

      Therefore, optimal inventory level is approximately 45 units.

      Extreme situation[ edit ]

      If




      p
      <
      c


      \displaystyle p<c

      (i.e. the retail price is less than the purchase price), the numerator becomes negative. In this situation, it isn’t worth keeping any items in the inventory.

      Derivation of optimal inventory level[ edit ]

      To derive the critical fractile formula, start with




      E


      [

      min

      q
      ,
      D


      ]



      \displaystyle \operatorname E \left[\min\q,D\\right]

      and condition on the event




      D

      q


      \displaystyle D\leq q

      :




      E

      [
      min

      q
      ,
      D

      ]
      =
      E

      [
      min

      q
      ,
      D


      D

      q
      ]
      P

      (
      D

      q
      )
      +
      E

      [
      min

      q
      ,
      D


      D
      >
      q
      ]
      P

      (
      D
      >
      q
      )
      =
      E

      [
      D

      D

      q
      ]
      F
      (
      q
      )
      +
      E

      [
      q

      D
      >
      q
      ]
      [
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      ]
      =
      E

      [
      D

      D

      q
      ]
      F
      (
      q
      )
      +
      q
      [
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      ]


      \displaystyle \operatorname E [\min\q,D\]=\operatorname E [\min\q,D\\mid D\leq q]\operatorname P (D\leq q)+\operatorname E [\min\q,D\\mid D>q]\operatorname P (D>q)=\operatorname E [D\mid D\leq q]F(q)+\operatorname E [q\mid D>q][1-F(q)]=\operatorname E [D\mid D\leq q]F(q)+q[1-F(q)]

      Now use




      E

      [
      D

      D

      q
      ]
      =






      x

      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x





      x

      q


      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x





      \displaystyle \operatorname E [D\mid D\leq q]=\frac \int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx\int \limits _x\leq qf(x)\,dx

      , where




      f
      (
      x
      )
      =

      F


      (
      x
      )


      \displaystyle f(x)=F'(x)

      . The denominator of this expression is




      F
      (
      q
      )


      \displaystyle F(q)

      , so now we can write:




      E

      [
      min

      q
      ,
      D

      ]
      =



      x

      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x
      +
      q
      [
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      ]


      \displaystyle \operatorname E [\min\q,D\]=\int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx+q[1-F(q)]

      So




      E

      [

      profit

      ]
      =
      p



      x

      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x
      +
      p
      q
      [
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      ]

      c
      q


      \displaystyle \operatorname E [\textprofit]=p\int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx+pq[1-F(q)]-cq

      Take the derivative with respect to




      q


      \displaystyle q

      :









      q



      E

      [

      profit

      ]
      =
      p
      q
      f
      (
      q
      )
      +
      p
      q
      (


      F


      (
      q
      )
      )
      +
      p
      [
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      ]

      c
      =
      p
      [
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      ]

      c


      \displaystyle \frac \partial \partial q\operatorname E [\textprofit]=pqf(q)+pq(-F'(q))+p[1-F(q)]-c=p[1-F(q)]-c

      Now optimize:




      p

      [

      1

      F
      (

      q




      )

      ]


      c
      =
      0

      1

      F
      (

      q




      )
      =


      c
      p



      F
      (

      q




      )
      =



      p

      c

      p




      q




      =

      F


      1



      (



      p

      c

      p


      )



      \displaystyle p\left[1-F(q^*)\right]-c=0\Rightarrow 1-F(q^*)=\frac cp\Rightarrow F(q^*)=\frac p-cp\Rightarrow q^*=F^-1\left(\frac p-cp\right)

      Technically, we should also check for convexity:









      2





      q

      2





      E

      [

      profit

      ]
      =
      p
      [


      F


      (
      q
      )
      ]


      \displaystyle \frac \partial ^2\partial q^2\operatorname E [\textprofit]=p[-F'(q)]

      Since




      F


      \displaystyle F

      is monotone non-decreasing, this second derivative is always non-positive, so the critical point determined above is a global maximum.

      Alternative formulation[ edit ]

      The problem above is cast as one of maximizing profit, although it can be cast slightly differently, with the same result. If the demand D exceeds the provided quantity q, then an opportunity cost of




      (
      D

      q
      )
      (
      p

      c
      )


      \displaystyle (D-q)(p-c)

      represents lost revenue not realized because of a shortage of inventory. On the other hand, if




      D

      q


      \displaystyle D\leq q

      , then (because the items being sold are perishable), there is an overage cost of




      (
      q

      D
      )
      c


      \displaystyle (q-D)c

      . This problem can also be posed as one of minimizing the expectation of the sum of the opportunity cost and the overage cost, keeping in mind that only one of these is ever incurred for any particular realization of




      D


      \displaystyle D

      . The derivation of this is as follows:









      E

      [

      opportunity cost

      +

      overage cost

      ]




      =




      E

      [

      overage cost


      D

      q
      ]
      P

      (
      D

      q
      )
      +
      E

      [

      opportunity cost


      D
      >
      q
      ]
      P

      (
      D
      >
      q
      )




      =




      E

      [
      (
      q

      D
      )
      c

      D

      q
      ]
      F
      (
      q
      )
      +
      E

      [
      (
      D

      q
      )
      (
      p

      c
      )

      D
      >
      q
      ]
      [
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      ]




      =




      c
      E

      [
      q

      D

      D

      q
      ]
      F
      (
      q
      )
      +
      (
      p

      c
      )
      E

      [
      D

      q

      D
      >
      q
      ]
      [
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      ]




      =




      c
      q
      F
      (
      q
      )

      c



      x

      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x
      +
      (
      p

      c
      )
      [



      x
      >
      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x

      q
      (
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      )
      ]




      =




      p



      x
      >
      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x

      p
      q
      (
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      )

      c



      x
      >
      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x
      +
      c
      q
      (
      1

      F
      (
      q
      )
      )
      +
      c
      q
      F
      (
      q
      )

      c



      x

      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x




      =




      p



      x
      >
      q


      x
      f
      (
      x
      )

      d
      x

      p
      q
      +
      p
      q
      F
      (
      q
      )
      +
      c
      q

      c
      E

      [
      D
      ]






      {\displaystyle {\beginaligned&\operatorname E [\textopportunity cost+\textoverage cost]\\[6pt]={}&\operatorname E [\textoverage cost\mid D\leq q]\operatorname P (D\leq q)+\operatorname E [\textopportunity cost\mid D>q]\operatorname P (D>q)\\[6pt]={}&\operatorname E [(q-D)c\mid D\leq q]F(q)+\operatorname E [(D-q)(p-c)\mid D>q][1-F(q)]\\[6pt]={}&c\operatorname E [q-D\mid D\leq q]F(q)+(p-c)\operatorname E [D-q\mid D>q][1-F(q)]\\[6pt]={}&cqF(q)-c\int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx+(p-c)[\int \limits _x>qxf(x)\,dx-q(1-F(q))]\\[6pt]={}&p\int \limits _x>qxf(x)\,dx-pq(1-F(q))-c\int \limits _x>qxf(x)\,dx+cq(1-F(q))+cqF(q)-c\int \limits _x\leq qxf(x)\,dx\\[6pt]={}&p\int \limits _x>qxf(x)\,dx-pq+pqF(q)+cq-c\operatorname E [D]\endaligned}}

      The derivative of this expression, with respect to




      q


      \displaystyle q

      , is









      q



      E

      [

      opportunity cost

      +

      overage cost

      ]
      =
      p
      (

      q
      f
      (
      q
      )
      )

      p
      +
      p
      q

      F


      (
      q
      )
      +
      p
      F
      (
      q
      )
      +
      c
      =
      p
      F
      (
      q
      )
      +
      c

      p


      \displaystyle \frac \partial \partial q\operatorname E [\textopportunity cost+\textoverage cost]=p(-qf(q))-p+pqF'(q)+pF(q)+c=pF(q)+c-p

      This is obviously the negative of the derivative arrived at above, and this is a minimization instead of a maximization formulation, so the critical point will be the same.

      Cost based optimization of inventory level[ edit ]

      Assume that the ‘newsvendor’ is in fact a small company that wants to produce goods to an uncertain market. In this more general situation the cost function of the newsvendor (company) can be formulated in the following manner:




      K
      (
      q
      )
      =

      c

      f


      +

      c

      v


      (
      q

      x
      )
      +
      p
      E


      [

      max
      (
      D

      q
      ,
      0
      )

      ]

      +
      h
      E


      [

      max
      (
      q

      D
      ,
      0
      )

      ]



      \displaystyle K(q)=c_f+c_v(q-x)+p\operatorname E \left[\max(D-q,0)\right]+h\operatorname E \left[\max(q-D,0)\right]

      where the individual parameters are the following:






      • c

        f




        \displaystyle c_f

        – fixed cost. This cost always exists when the production of a series is started. [$/production]






      • c

        v




        \displaystyle c_v

        – variable cost. This cost type expresses the production cost of one product. [$/product]





      • q


        \displaystyle q

        – the product quantity in the inventory. The decision of the inventory control policy concerns the product quantity in the inventory after the product decision. This parameter includes the initial inventory as well. If nothing is produced, then this quantity is equal to the initial quantity, i.e. concerning the existing inventory.





      • x


        \displaystyle x

        – initial inventory level. We assume that the supplier possesses




        x


        \displaystyle x

        products in the inventory at the beginning of the demand of the delivery period.





      • p


        \displaystyle p

        – penalty cost (or back order cost). If there is less raw material in the inventory than needed to satisfy the demands, this is the penalty cost of the unsatisfied orders. [$/product]





      • D


        \displaystyle D

        – a random variable with cumulative distribution function




        F


        \displaystyle F

        representing uncertain customer demand. [unit]





      • E
        [
        D
        ]


        \displaystyle E[D]

        – expected value of random variable




        D


        \displaystyle D

        .





      • h


        \displaystyle h

        – inventory and stock holding cost. [$ / product]

      In




      K
      (
      q
      )


      \displaystyle K(q)

      , the first order loss function




      E

      [

      max
      (
      D

      q
      ,
      0
      )

      ]



      \displaystyle E\left[\max(D-q,0)\right]

      captures the expected shortage quantity; its complement,




      E

      [

      max
      (
      q

      D
      ,
      0
      )

      ]



      \displaystyle E\left[\max(q-D,0)\right]

      , denotes the expected product quantity in stock at the end of the period. [6]

      On the basis of this cost function the determination of the optimal inventory level is a minimization problem. So in the long run the amount of cost-optimal end-product can be calculated on the basis of the following relation: [1]





      q

      opt


      =

      F


      1



      (



      p


      c

      v




      p
      +
      h



      )



      \displaystyle q_\textopt=F^-1\left(\frac p-c_vp+h\right)

      Data-driven models[ edit ]

      There are several data-driven model for the newsvendor problem. Among them, a deep learning model provides quite stable results in any kind of non-noisy or volatile data. [7]

      See also[ edit ]

      • Infinite fill rate for the part being produced: Economic order quantity
      • Constant fill rate for the part being produced: Economic production quantity
      • Demand varies over time: Dynamic lot size model
      • Several products produced on the same machine: Economic lot scheduling problem
      • Reorder point
      • Inventory control system
      • Extended newsvendor model

      References[ edit ]

      1. ^ a b William J. Stevenson, Operations Management. 10th edition, 2009; page 581
      2. ^ F. Y. Edgeworth (1888). “The Mathematical Theory of Banking”. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. 51 (1): 113–127. JSTOR   2979084 .

      3. ^ Guillermo Gallego (18 Jan 2005). “IEOR 4000 Production Management Lecture 7” (PDF). Columbia University . Retrieved 30 May 2012.
      4. ^ R. R. Chen; T.C.E. Cheng; T.M. Choi; Y. Wang (2016). “Novel Advances in Applications of the Newsvendor Model”. Decision Sciences. 47: 8–10.
      5. ^ K. J. Arrow, T. Harris, Jacob Marshak, Optimal Inventory Policy, Econometrica 1951
      6. ^ Axsäter, Sven (2015). Inventory Control (3rd ed.). Springer International Publishing. ISBN   978-3-319-15729-0 .
      7. ^ Oroojlooyjadid, Afshin; Snyder, Lawrence; Takáč, Martin (2016-07-07). “Applying Deep Learning to the Newsvendor Problem”. arXiv : 1607.02177 [ cs.LG ].

      Further reading[ edit ]

      • Ayhan, Hayriye, Dai, Jim, Foley, R. D., Wu, Joe, 2004: Newsvendor Notes, ISyE 3232 Stochastic Manufacturing & Service Systems. [1]
      • Tsan-Ming Choi (Ed.) Handbook of Newsvendor Problems: Models, Extensions and Applications, in Springer’s International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, 2012.

      Retrieved from ” https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Newsvendor_model&oldid=846789040 ”
      Categories :

      • Inventory optimization

      Navigation menu

      Personal tools

      • Not logged in
      • Talk
      • Contributions
      • Create account
      • Log in

      Namespaces

      • Article
      • Talk

      Variants

        Views

        • Read
        • Edit
        • View history

        More


          Navigation

          • Main page
          • Contents
          • Featured content
          • Current events
          • Random article
          • Donate to Wikipedia
          • Wikipedia store

          Interaction

          • Help
          • About Wikipedia
          • Community portal
          • Recent changes
          • Contact page

          Tools

          • What links here
          • Related changes
          • Upload file
          • Special pages
          • Permanent link
          • Page information
          • Wikidata item
          • Cite this page

          Print/export

          • Create a book
          • Download as PDF
          • Printable version

          Languages

          • Deutsch
          • Español
          • Euskara
          • Français
          • Italiano
          • Polski
          • Português
          Edit links

          • This page was last edited on 20 June 2018, at 22:12 (UTC).
          • Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License ;
            additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy . Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc. , a non-profit organization.
          • Privacy policy
          • About Wikipedia
          • Disclaimers
          • Contact Wikipedia
          • Developers
          • Cookie statement
          • Mobile view
          • Wikimedia Foundation
          • Powered by MediaWiki